return to homepage Ben Stein v. Paul Krugman by Miles Mathis Most people who arrive at this
article in the natural way—that is, by coming via my homepage or via some other
previous knowledge of me—will expect that they know which side I am going to be
on here. I am mostly a lefty once I
put my paintbrush down, therefore I must be intending to defend Krugman. Krugman attacks Bush constantly, I despise
Bush, so it isn’t too hard to figure out. However, those who know me even better know that nothing
bores me more than doing what is expected of me. They know that I would never bother to write an article that
moved in a predictable path. The two
main paths in the current bilateral argument are already well represented, and
I have no need to add to the mountains of literature on either side. Therefore I must be entering this argument
from some strange obtuse angle, from some idealistic and possibly naïve dirt
track, from some cliff that I will—at some point in the argument,
guaranteed—appear to be hanging by the tips of my fingernails. . .. Well, those people are
right. They are right because I am
limiting myself here to one exchange between Stein and Krugman, the famous New
York Times exchange from March of 2002.
To jog the memory of most and to update the memory of the rest, Krugman
had written a short memorial and commentary to the economist James Tobin. In that commentary, Krugman claimed that
most agreed that the Great Depression was caused by laissez-faire
policies. He then called Milton
Friedman “naïve” and claimed that monetarism was a dead letter. Finally, Krugman used the commentary to sell
Tobin’s brand of neo-Keynesianism, which he labeled “sophisticated.” Ben Stein called him on the first two statements and then
famously accused Krugman of having “a limited background in economics.” Krugman did not respond to Stein’s arguments, being
satisfied with calling him a gameshow host, and stating that he, Krugman, knew
both Tobin and the subject of economics more intimately than Stein. Everyone on the left was
certain that Stein had lost this exchange, and no one on the right disagreed
with that. Many on the right took up
Stein’s arguments, but no one defended Stein.
The consensus was, and apparently is, that Krugman “owned” Stein in the
mini-debate. Well, economics is not my long suit, and I don’t mind
leading with that admission. I can
admit that both Krugman and Stein know a lot more about economics than I do, since
it won’t much affect my article here.
In fact, I will state for the record that I think the importance of
economics as a whole has been vastly oversold in the 20th
century. I find it vulgar for anyone
but the poor to be so interested in money.
If you have rent to pay and food to buy, and you have some immediate
concern that you cannot pay it or buy it, then you have some right to be
concerned with money. You may still be
vulgar, but at least you have some excuse for it. In the modern world you have some very pressing reasons to doubt
that what the fowls of the air get for free, you will also get, free or
otherwise. But when rich people spend years studying economics, it must
be suspect. I have never met nor heard
tell of an economist who recommended that other people should get rich before him
and his friends and family, or who recommended that money was unimportant, or
who recommended that a government should be as small as possible and disburse
immediately and equally everything it took in. And yes, I mean this to apply to Marxist economists and all
others as well as to capitalists. If
you talk about money all the time, you must be interested in it, and if you are
interested in it, it is unlikely that your interest evolved from a pressing
desire to give it away. Krugman can claim that someone whose career centers upon
critiquing government policy must know something about economics, and this is
true. But critiquing the government may
take many forms, and there is no reason to assume that this critique must
closely orbit economics. For instance,
Ruskin knew quite a bit about economics, but he used that knowledge to advance
theories that were not mainly economic in nature. The same can be said of someone like Emerson, who has been a very
influential voice in American history.
Both knew that economics was a necessary ingredient of government
policy, but they recognized that no government can be grounded in economic
policy, much less the society that government governs. No doubt all quarters will attack me as hopelessly stuck in
the past. How could anyone bring up
Emerson and Ruskin when presented with Friedman and Keynes? Don’t I know that economics has reached a
level of “sophistication” that is lightyears beyond anything Ruskin or Emerson
could have imagined? Yes, I do know
that claim is made, since Krugman just made it. Nor is he the first. It
is current wisdom that current wisdom is everything and that the past has been
superceded. But if Krugman can be
nostalgic about the 60’s, when Tobin was in the Council of Economic Advisors
and people “of fundamental decency” could exist, I suppose I can be nostalgic
about the 19th century, when writers, critics, and analysts could
call themselves idealists without having that immediately translated as
“ideologues.” What I mean by
that, specifically, is that most commentators in the 19th century
would have been embarrassed to be caught basing any argument on economics. Both a society and a government were
expected to have deeper foundations. I
am not saying that all or even most commentators in the 19th century
proposed or argued for the right foundations, but they understood that the
argument must go deeper than monetarism or inflation targeting or asset prices
or aggregates. And they understood
that this deeper level was not arrived at by putting a WWJD bumper sticker on
your car or telling people that you “talked to God.” Obviously that last hit was at
Bush, not Krugman, and I will be asked to stay on target. Well, the previous paragraphs hit all
targets, as they were meant to. The
first problem with the Stein/Krugman mini-debate is that it never got off the
ground. An economic argument is stale
to begin with, and one that never evolves into real questions of intent is
doubly stale. By this standard both Stein
and Krugman are losers. I chose their
argument mainly as an example of the current level. Like the Buckley/Galbraith debate of a generation ago, this one
never reaches altitude.
Buckley/Galbraith at least got off the ground. It reached treetop level, let off a couple of sonic booms, then
stalled out and crashed with a thud.
This one simply hits the fence at the end of the runway and rips up a
swath of knee-high corn. Despite that, I am going to try to kick it into the air
for a few moments, like a half-aired beachball, to see if we can get a few
kernels of real information from it. Stein’s first contention is
that the Great Depression was not caused by laissez-faire economics, and
that everyone knows that. Is he
correct? I will not argue about what
everyone knows or does not know, since I don’t give a damn. What the majority thinks of the matter, or
how accurately Stein or Krugman mirror the majority, is not the question at
hand. The question concerns the term laissez-faire,
and the historical fact. It seems to
me that the problem in this cross-fire is that neither Stein nor Krugman makes
any effort to say what he means by the term, and that it appears they mean two
separate things. I think Krugman
implies that the Great Depression was caused by the federal government refusing
to take strong control of the situation.
If the feds don’t take a firm control of the market, then they are
“letting it be,” which is laissez-faire, simply by translation from the
French. Both sides seem to admit that this is the case, since
Stein blames the New Deal for the Depression.
A feature of the New Deal was to allow the problem to correct itself, so
that the fix would be a permanent one.
However, it appears to me that Stein may be implying that other forces
were at work. If he is not, he should
be. He says that the New Deal included
price-fixing and restraint of trade. He
could mean one of two things by that.
He may mean to criticize Roosevelt for not allowing the “free market” to
determine things even more than he did.
This is the standard Republican critique, and as such is a complete
misdirection. But he could mean that Roosevelt mainly continued the regressive
policies of his predecessors. Depending
on when and how they are done, price-fixing and trade restraint can either help
the rich or hurt them. Is the price
being fixed high or low? Is it being
fixed when the middle classes have a lot of the money in the country or when
the rich do? What trade is being
restrained and why? For it is not simply a matter of strong government
control or laissez-faire: it is not one or the other. You can argue that no part of the Depression
was laissez-faire by arguing that the government simply refused to
override other pre-existing controls.
The government can pretty much let the market be, but this does not mean
that the market is sailing along free of control. What it means is that it is under the control of the banks, which
were not then and are not now owned or controlled by the government. If this is what Stein means, then he is
correct. Krugman will say that I am naïve in trying to argue that
letting the rich determine the market is not laissez-faire, since that
is precisely what it is. In a state of
nature, where all controls are removed, the rich will naturally determine the
markets. He will say that I cannot
undercut the term laissez-faire by inserting the word “control” in that
way. And now we are getting to the heart of it. The beachball is finally rising into the
air. For this brings us to the
distinction that Krugman and Stein never reach, that no one ever reaches in the
mainstream press. From the time of Woodrow Wilson, the government had been
actively assisting the rich (I could say from the time of Washington, but I am
concerned here only with the Depression and its immediate causes). The Federal Reserve didn’t set itself up in
some vacuum or in a milieu of laissez-faire. It wasn’t some necessary and natural market outcome. There was much debate, there were votes in
Congress, the charters were written and signed. The banks were given control of the market by the
government of the United States, over the express outcries of many vocal
legislators and analysts and critics.
That is not laissez-faire, that is policy. Roosevelt did not change that policy and it
is still the policy today. A complete
lack of government control over the markets does not take us to a state of
nature, it takes us to plutocratic tyranny.
I may be overly generous in assuming that Stein intended to
allude to any of that. It would seem
strange to see a conservative arguing against policies for the rich, but Stein
has done it before (or I should say since).
Stein has been attacked for his article in the Sunday Times [May
7, 2006] entitled, “You’re rich?
Terrific. Now Pay Up!” Lest you think that Stein, demoralized by
his loss to Krugman, switched sides in the four years since 2002, I must
recommend you read the article, which also tells us—apropos of nothing—that the
oil companies are not price fixing and that they are doing a great job. No, Stein is still a conservative, but he
does buck the line sometimes, and I think that this argument with Krugman might
have been one of those times. But no matter what
Stein was alluding to, he was correct regarding Krugman. The Great Depression was not caused by laissez-faire,
even if you accept that Hoover and Roosevelt did not take firm control of the
situation in any way. Even if it were
proved that they did absolutely nothing, policy-wise, it is still easy to show
that the markets were not free. To say
that the government was not controlling the situation is not to say that no one
was controlling it; and unless the government had decided to dissolve the
Federal Reserve Board, we should expect that those who were controlling it
before 1929 were still controlling it after 1929. Now on to the next
question. Was Milton Friedman
naïve? I don’t like Friedman any more
than I like Keynes, but I don’t think naïve is the correct adjective. What Krugman meant is that Friedman was
wrong, and he should have just said so.
The word naïve displays a smugness when it is used, in almost every
situation, and certainly in this situation, and I think Stein was correct to
call him on it. Krugman proves this in
his reply, where he continues to argue smugly.
Krugman has every right to disagree with Friedman: his
own knowledge of economics justifies his public opinion in the biggest newspaper
in the country. But that level of
knowledge does not justify looking down his nose at Friedman. Friedman reached a level in the field
second to none, and to assert that he reached that level with a naïve
understanding of his subject is disingenuous.
It is even counterproductive, since it implies that he may have been too
simple or unaware to intend the outcomes of his policies. I believe that Friedman fully understood
what he was doing and why: that is why he is fully responsible for his books,
his counsel, and the outcomes of that counsel. The truth
is, none of these people are naïve or ill-informed. They are all extremely well-read, very intelligent, and quite
capable of building an argument from top to bottom or bottom to top. All this argument about who knows more facts
or who knew whom more intimately or who was whose Daddy is feckless. If these smart people are going to argue
with each other, they should do us the favor of debating some real issues. And if they want to do that, they are going
to have to dig deeper than economics.
Economic policy is always chosen for a reason, and a real debate will
have to air these reasons. OK, next question: is
monetarism dead? Well, again, I think
we are seeing two different definitions being batted about. Krugman says in his memorial that Keynes
showed us that “with judicious use of monetary and fiscal policy a free
market system could avoid future depressions.”
Is that not a sort of monetarism? In any economic theory, a vital part of
“monetary policy” is going to be money supply.
Krugman intends monetarism to be read in the strictest sense, so that it
applies only to how much money is printed and in supply. Stein means to imply, I think, that although
this may not be the only thing that is important in money policy, it is still
one of the primary concerns of any economics.
It may be correct that money supply does not completely determine
inflation or anything else, but no one would argue that you can print as much
or as little money as you like with no market effect. Friedman tied money supply to inflation but never said that it
was the only tie. Krugman makes it look
black and white in his memorial: he implies that Friedman’s
theory—monetarism—was concerned only with money supply, that it ignored all
other factors, and that it has been made completely obsolete in the last 20
years. I wish it were so, but agree
with Stein that it isn’t. For the record,
I also wish that Keynes’ theory were completely obsolete, or that it had reached
a laudable level of sophistication. But
it isn’t and it hasn’t. Large parts of
both Keynes’ and Friedman’s theories are intact to this day, sometimes
modified, sometimes almost pristine. To
say that Friedman has become obsolete is like claiming that Freud is obsolete,
simply because no one is a Freudian like Freud was. In the end I usually side with
Krugman, since he is attacking Bush for reasons that transcend economics. Those reasons might be called moral,
although that word has been sullied in the past century. But in this debate I have to side with
Stein, since Stein is mainly correct in the points he offers in the
letter. The Depression was not caused
by laissez-faire policies, Friedman was not naïve, and monetarism is not
dead. Most have said that Stein was “owned” by Krugman in this
debate, but I think a more precise word would have been “pre-owned.” That is, Krugman won only because he sat in
a higher position at the beginning of the debate, and could loft his words
downwards upon his opponent. But I am
not impressed with tactics like that.
Both of Krugman’s letters (the memorial to Tobin and the reply to Stein)
stink of authority. It is bad enough
that Stein mentions his dad; much worse that Krugman mentions his Clark
Medal. Unfortunately, this is now the state of the art in
economics. Even at the highest levels,
the discussions are all misdirection, on both sides. Here is one of my favorite quotes on this, from Webster Tarpley: The
economics profession is totally bankrupt today, with every Nobel Prize winner
in economics with the sole exception of Maurice Allais qualifying for commitment
to a psychiatric institution. One of the reasons for the depravity of the
economists is that their assigned task has always been one of mystification,
especially the job of covering up the simple and brutal fact that American
depressions have generally been caused by Bank of England and City of London
bankers. I recommend that last assertion
of Tarpley as a topic for debate by Stein and Krugman. At the least, they need to address some real
questions instead of these make-work questions about Friedman and aggregates
and monetarism. Let them finally graduate
beyond sophomoric preening and semantic trivialities. As a low-level warm-up, let Stein take the position of Friedman,
or any update of it he chooses, and let Krugman take the position of a
“sophisticated” neo-Keynesian, and let us see where it takes them. I think to make it interesting they must
address what sort of society Keynes and Friedman intended their economies to
underwrite, and what sort of society Stein and Krugman envision. Without that, the debate will never get
above treetop level, no matter how much wind they blow past our ears. If this paper was useful to you in any way, please consider donating a dollar (or more) to the SAVE THE ARTISTS FOUNDATION. This will allow me to continue writing these "unpublishable" things. Don't be confused by paying Melisa Smith--that is just one of my many noms de plume. If you are a Paypal user, there is no fee; so it might be worth your while to become one. Otherwise they will rob us 33 cents for each transaction. |